Skip navigation

Corporations Go to Prison Labor Studies Journal 2002

Download original document:
Brief thumbnail
This text is machine-read, and may contain errors. Check the original document to verify accuracy.
Corporations Go to Prisons: The Expansion of
Corporate Power in the Correctional Industry
Tracy F. H. Chang and Douglas E. Thompkins
Abstract
Over the last two decades, the U.S. prison population has quadrupled, with some 1.9 million people behind bars in federal and
state prisons, and local jails by the year 2000. Corporations are
seeking profit-making opportunities from this prison population.
In this paper, we examine two major areas through which corporations are capitalizing on prison labor: prison privatization and prison
industry. We briefly review key explanations of incarceration, report on the current state of prison privatization and prison industrialization, examine the impact they have on organized labor, and
propose union strategies in fighting against the expansion of corporate power in the correctional industry.

I

n the last two decades, the U.S. prison population has quadrupled (see
Figure 1). In 1980, the federal and state prisons and local jails together
held a total of 500,000 people, but by 2000 the prison and jail population
had surged to 1.9 million (Beck and Harrison, 2001). This explosion in
prison population has become both a force for, and a product of, the
“prison industrial complex,” a convergence of the economic and political
interests of exalting corporate profits and elite power from incarceration
(Davis, 2000; Parenti, 1999; Schlosser, 1998). The term is used to describe
the magnitude of the involvement of private, for-profit enterprise in the
corrections system. The prison industrial complex comprises two major
segments: prison privatization and prison industrialization. The expansion
of these two processes has generated many controversies in recent years.
In the following sections, we will briefly review key theories of
incarceration, present the recent development of, and issues concerning,
———————
LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL, Vol. 27, No. 1 (Spring 2002). Published for the United Association
for Labor Education by the West Virginia University Press, Press, P.O. Box 6295, West
Virginia University, Morgantown, WV 26506. © 2002, West Virginia University Press.

45

46

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

47

private prisons and the prison industry. We also discuss their impact on
organized labor and union strategies in fighting against the expansion of
corporate power in the correction system.
The Political Economy of Incarceration
Criminologists have found that increases in the unemployment rate,
poverty, income inequality, racial conflict, and political conservatism contribute to an increase in the incarceration rate, independent of the crime
rate (Barlow and Johnson, 1996; Hochstetler and Shover, 1997; Jacobs
and Helms, 1996; Mauer, 1999). These findings support the theory that,
to preserve their advantage in the class, racial, and social hierarchies, the
dominant classes use imprisonment as a means of political, economic,
and social control over the “dangerous classes”: the unemployed, the poor,
the homeless, the mentally ill, the political dissidents, and the racial,
ethnic, and social “others” (Jacobs and Helms, 1996; Parenti, 1999;
Sheldon, 2001). In essence, class struggle manifests itself in the form of
crime control and imprisonment (Parenti, 1999). When unemployment
is low, the state relaxes imprisonment to allow sufficient labor to compete
for wages in the free market; when unemployment is high, the state imprisons greater numbers to absorb surplus labor and suppress social unrest
associated with economic deprivation. Barlow (1996) found that when
the economy stagnates, Congress passes more federal laws that add additional activities as criminal offenses, mandates more severe penalties, and
demands more strict law enforcement. Jacobs and Helms (1996) documented that, compared to Democrats, Republican presidents since 1935
have established a record of campaigning on a “tough on crime” platform
to attract lower- and working-class voters. They also increase federal criminal justice expenditures and advocate anti-crime bills, both of which tend
to increase the nation’s incarceration rate.
Conflict criminologists explain the racial disparity in incarceration
rates, a major characteristic of the U.S. criminal justice system, in economic, political, and racial terms. African-Americans comprise 12 percent of the U.S. population but they represent 46 percent of the prison
population (Beck and Harrison, 2001). Their disproportional share of the
prison population is related to the fact that they disproportionately belong to the economic underclass that is plagued by poverty and unemployment. The racial gap in incarceration is further widened by racial bias
in each area of the criminal justice system (judiciary, law enforcement,
and corrections) (Mauer, 1999).
To understand the soaring incarceration of the last two decades,

48

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

criminologists point to declining economic conditions and increasing income inequality, racial tension, political conservatism, anti-crime legislation, and economic globalization during this period. Between 1979 and
1983, the national unemployment rated increased by 66 percent. The
income gap between the rich and poor increased by 22 percent between
1968 and 1994, with drastic increases in the 1980s and 1990s (Weinberg,
1996). Although millions of new jobs were created in the 1990s, most
were non-union and low wage jobs in the service sector. The unemployment rate was decreasing but, especially among black males, it was underestimated by the exclusion of the prison population (Western and Pettit,
2000). Other criminologists argue that in the 1990s the global capitalists
can find alternative and less rebellious low-wage labor, immigrants, and
Third World workers, so the state can use incarceration as a means of
economic, social, and political exclusion of African-Americans (Hagedorn,
1998).
Ronald Reagan not only conducted the most anti-labor administration since the 1920s, his administration also launched an era of unprecedented “criminal justice militarization”—the war on crime and on drugs
(Parenti, 1999). The Comprehensive Crime Control Act of 1984 and the
Anti-Drug Abuse Act of 1986 and 1988, escalated the anti-crime and
drug war by increasing the federal criminal justice budget and promoting
anti-offender mandatory sentencing policies, law enforcement practices,
and judicial processes (Parenti, 1999). Inheriting the anti-crime political
legacy of three Republican administrations, the “New Democrat” Bill
Clinton advocated and signed the Violent Crime Control and Law Enforcement Act of 1994. The bill created new federal crimes, mandated
more severe minimum sentences, enforced border control, and budgeted
$30 billion to hire 100,000 new police officers and to construct new prisons. The anti-drug war has resulted in broader definitions of illegal drugs,
more arrests, more prosecutions, and longer mandatory minimum sentences of drug users and sellers, which increased the number of Latino
and African-Americans in prison (Mauer, 1999). The number of drug
offenders in federal and state prisons increased by 1,000 percent between
1980 and 1997. Forty-five percent of drug offenders are Latinos, 28 percent are African-Americans, and 25 percent are whites (Scalia, 2001).
The soaring prison population inspired entrepreneurs seeking business opportunities. Corporations began to seek multi-million dollar contracts with state governments in constructing, managing, and operating
prisons. Federal and state governments, and private sectors began to expand the employment of inmates for profitable production and services.

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

49

During the 1990s, the “prison industrial complex” became one of the
most profitable growth industries (Schlosser, 1998). We now examine the
recent development of prison privatization and prison industrialization
and the issues raised by this development.
Prison Privatization
Political Context and Recent Development
The idea and practice of “privatization,” delegating public duties to
private organizations, gained popularity when Reagan gained electoral
support by advocating the idea of small government and free market
economy. Concurrently, the rising prison population was overcrowding
correctional facilities and consuming government budgets nationwide. By
1984, the federal prisons were overcrowded by 10 to 37 percent and the
state prisons nationwide were operating at five to 16 percent over capacity. The congested prisons and jails engendered hazardous health and safety
conditions, inmate idleness and violence, and the increasing government
spending on corrections generated public discontent. The total spending
on state prisons surged by 74 percent in only four years, from $4.5 billion
in 1980 to $7.7 billion in 1984 (Donahue, 1989). In 1996 state governments spent $29 billion in corrections (Bureau of Justice Statistics, 2000).
Free citizens demanded tough crime control and harsh punishment, but
resented spending their tax dollars on incarceration. These prison and
budget crises energized entrepreneurs to start correctional corporations to
manage and operate the nation’s prisons.
Prison privatization requires collaboration among business leaders,
elected state officials, political party elites, and correctional experts. Elected
officials were attracted to what corporations promised: to absorb the soaring incarceration rate while saving taxpayers money. They began to pass
laws allowing privatization during the early 1980s. A firm may build a
facility, and usually own it, with a governmental agency contract to house
inmates on a per diem or monthly fee basis. Or, a firm may build a facility
without a contract in the hope of obtaining emergency contracts at a
higher rate. A firm may also manage, operate, or purchase a new or existing federal, state, or local facility (AFSCME, 2001). Presently, 28 states
have statutory authority for private prisons and only two states, Illinois
and New York, have a statutory prohibition on prison privatization. Ten
other states have interpreted prison privatization as “permissive” rather
than “prohibitive” (see Appendix I) (Thomas, 2000). Unless a state passes
a prohibition statute, a firm can build a prison in the state and contract

50

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

with the federal government or with other states to take their prisoners
(Schneider, 2000).
The Corrections Corporation of America (CCA) was the first, and
is currently the largest, correctional corporation, holding over 50 percent
of the U.S. market, as well as international operations. Founded in 1983
and based in Nashville, Tennessee, CCA was well connected politically,
financially, and technically to lobby aggressively for lucrative contracts.
Its co-founder, Thomas W. Beasley, was the former chairman of the Tennessee State Republican Party. T. Don Hutto, who provides technical
expertise for the company, is the former head of the American Correctional Association and commissioner of corrections departments in Virginia and Arkansas. Several high-ranking state officials also owned CCA
stock (Schneider, 2000). In 1989, CCA contracted 3,448 beds. Now, with
15,000 employees, the company manages 75 facilities with 77,500 beds in
21 states, and owns 50 facilities in the U.S., Puerto Rico, England, France,
and Australia. CCA became a publicly traded company in 1986. It showed
an annual growth rate of 70 percent from 1992 through 1997, ranking as
one of the five top performers on the New York Stock Exchange (Mobley
and Geis, 2001; Parenti, 1999).
In the last 13 years, the capacity of private prisons has grown from
3,122 to 142,000 beds, an average annual increase of 300 percent. At
present, 31 states have active contracts with private correctional firms
(Thomas, 2000). In 2000, privately operated prisons held more than 101,000
federal and state prisoners and local jail inmates, representing 11 percent
of all federal prisoners, six percent of all state prisoners, and two percent
of jail inmates (Beck and Harrison, 2001). The majority of private operations (63 percent) were concentrated in the southern states, where conservative politics prevail, followed by the western states (22 percent) (see
Figure 2). Texas has the highest private prison capacity with 30,000 beds
and the largest number of inmates (14,000) housed in private facilities.
In contrast to public prisons, private prisons operate at 90 percent
of their capacity (The Criminal Justice Institute, 2000). The under-capacity of private, for-profit correctional facilities seems counterintuitive.
Corporations build prisons faster than do public agencies (Schneider, 2000).
It is plausible that private firms build prisons faster than they can secure
contracts with public agencies, especially when they face strong grassroots
movements against prison privatization (Donahue, 1989; Hallett and Lee,
2001). On the other hand, the under-capacity may be by design to obtain
more lucrative emergency contracts.

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

51

Issues of Prison Privatization
Social and political activists oppose prison privatization for various
reasons. Organized labor’s prime objection is the formidable threat posed
by privatization on its members and on union strength in the public
sector. The AFL-CIO and its affiliate American Federation of State,
County, and Municipal Employees (AFSCME) have persistently made
public statements that “oppose the privatization of prisons at the local,
state, and federal level” (AFL-CIO, 2001; AFSCME, 2001). AFSCME,
representing 80,000 correctional officers and employees (AFSCME Correction United), is a leader in the fight against prison privatization across
the country.
Proponents of prison privatization claim that it lowers the cost of
incarceration, which offers a solution to government fiscal crisis. However, studies show that the cost reduction is miniscule and often is achieved

52

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

by sacrificing service and staff qualities (Donahue, 1989; Schneider, 2000).
Furthermore, the cost comparison often overlooks the “hidden” cost associated with accountability and public safety (AFSCME, 2001). The cost
of employee salary and benefits is the largest expenditure item in the
corrections budget, consuming over 60 percent of costs (Bureau of Justice
Statistics, 2000). To be profitable, the companies must first reduce labor
costs by paying employees lower wages and benefits, and eliminating unionization. Recent statistics indicate that the entry-level annual salary for
correctional officers averages $23,000 in the public sector and $18,000 in
the private sector. The maximum-level averages $36,000 in the public
sector and $22,000 in the private sector (The Criminal Justice Institute,
2000). While cutting employee wages and benefits, private prisons boost
executive pay and benefits. In 2000, the maximum salary of directors of
public correctional agencies was $129,000 while the CEO pay of CCA is
$213,000, with five million shares of stock options.
Researchers also warn that lower labor costs often lead to lower
quality and stability of the workforce. Public guards are far more likely to
be high school graduates, to work full-time and year-round at their jobs,
and to be of prime working age (Donahue, 1989). The turnover rate of
correctional officers in the public sector is 16 percent versus 52 percent in
the private sector. And, the public sector provides 250 hours of pre-service training, while the private sector provides 153 hours (The Criminal
Justice Institute, 2000). The conditions of lower-pay, less training, and
higher turnover rate invite corruption, inmate abuse, less prison security,
and threats to public safety, creating a “hidden” cost of lawsuits and inmate escapes (AFSCME, 2001).
Privatization also depresses correctional officers and employees’ wages,
benefits, and working conditions, and threatens union power by displacing unionized correctional employees in the public sector (Donahue, 1989).
Chandler (1994) found that privatization of public services reduces the
union wage advantage because unions tend to temper their wage demand.
Unions lose bargaining leverage when alternative lower-cost labor becomes available. When the union wage premium decreases, organizing
new members becomes more difficult (Hirsch and Schumacher, 2001).
The growth of government jobs associated with rising incarceration
offered the labor movement an advantageous opportunity for unionizing,
but substantial privatization could endanger the prospect of successful
organizing by transferring jobs to the private sector where organizing is
more difficult. The “tough on crime” political platform has generated
employment in the criminal justice system at the federal, state, and local

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

53

levels. Between 1982 and 1997, the police employment of all government
levels increased by 31 percent (from 700,000 to 950,000) and the corrections employment increased by 138 percent (from 270,000 to 700,000).
The protective occupation (correctional officers, fire fighters, guards, police and detectives, and private detectives and investigators) is the most
highly unionized occupational group, with a union density of 39 percent
(Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2000). As demand for correctional workers
rises, public correctional employee’s unions gain strength and are able to
bargain higher wages and benefits for their members. In 1996, average
annual earnings for unionized correction officers was $33,000, compared
to $24,000 for non-union correction officers (Wright, 1997).
The problems of prison privatization go well beyond economic issues. Political and social progressives focus on the accountability and democratic control of the corrections system. The American Bar Association
addresses the unconstitutionality of delegating coercive power and authority of punishment for crime—an essential government function—to
private hands. The courts have not yet resolved the issue of whether
private administrators have the legal authority to make quasi-judicial decisions concerning the length or the conditions of confinement, and to
take disciplinary actions against prisoners (e.g., deprivation of privileges
or solitary confinement) (Parenti, 1999). Human and civil rights groups
emphasize the moral and ethical issues. For-profit firms may put profit
motives ahead of the interests of the public and inmates, and the purpose
of imprisonment. To expand their markets, it is in the interest of private
correctional companies to deny inmates due process, lengthen their prison
time, and lobby for laws and policies that create more imprisonment.
Schneider (2000) found that states with more private contracts in 1996
had higher rates of incarceration in 1997, when the factor of state budget
was controlled.
Organized labor and its allies’ strenuous lobbying against prison privation has deterred the expansion of prison privatization. In 1985, despite CCA’s powerful political connections and the public’s favorable opinion about prison privatization, intense lobbying from the Tennessee State
Employees Association (TSEA), Tennessee Bar Association, Tennessee
Trial Lawyers, and ACLU halted CCA’s bid to operate its home state’s
prisons (Schneider, 2000). The California Correctional Peace Officers
Association (CCPOA) pioneered the battle against prison privatization
in California. With its rich financial resources, strong organization, vigorous lobbying, and involvement with the victims’ rights movement,
CCPOA has achieved impressive results in stalling privatization (Parenti,

54

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

1999). Although California has the largest prison population, the portion of inmates held in private facilities lags behind 24 other states (see
Appendix I).
In most states, AFSCME leads the fight. The national union disseminates research results, data and statistics, articles, and news on prison
privatization through the Internet, printed publications, and videotapes.
The union also involves thousands of its rank-and-file members in marches,
protests, and lobbying across the country from Pennsylvania, Wisconsin,
Nebraska, Iowa, Ohio, to Tennessee (Parenti, 1999). CCA’s multiple attempts to take over Tennessee’s entire prison system in 1997 and 1998
were defeated by a coalition of religious organizations, students groups,
and 2,000 prison guards mobilized in front of the TSEA at the governor’s
office and the CCA world headquarters (Hallett and Lee, 2001). At its
107th Congress, AFSCME secured the support of the National Black Caucus of State Legislators, the Fraternal Order of Police, and other organizations in lobbying for the Public Safety Act, prohibiting privatization of
federal prisons.
Prison Industrialization
Historical Background
The modern era of American prison labor began in 1790 when the
Walnut Street Jail in Philadelphia contracted its prisoners out to private
business for profitable production. By 1885, there were six systems of
prison labor: (1) the contract, (2) the piece-price, (3) the lease, (4) the
state-account, (5) the state-use system, and (6) public works and ways
(Barnes and Teeters, 1943). Under the contract system, private contractors furnished the machinery and the raw material and supervised the
prisoners’ work inside the prison under the surveillance of the state prison
guards. The piece-price system is a variation of the contract system—
contractors provided the raw materials and paid the state for each piece
produced by its prisoners. In 1825, the “lease system” became widely adopted
in the South as a substitute for African slavery in agricultural production.
Under the lease system, inmate labor was sold to the highest bidder for a
fixed period; the private entrepreneur assumed entire control of prisoners, including their labor, food, clothing, shelter, and discipline. Under
the state-account and state-use systems, the state assumed the role of the
entrepreneur, operating and managing the production and labor processes,
and assuming all financial risks and gains. The only difference is that the
state-account system sold products on the open market, but the state-use

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

55

system sold products only to their own institutions or other state agencies. Public works and ways projects use inmates in the construction of
roads, railways, public buildings, and even other prisons.
Organized labor, along with manufacturers’ associations, saw prison
labor as unfair competition and had been protesting against it since its
inception. During the 1880s, the National Labor Union denounced convict labor at its first conventions; and the Federation of Organized Trades
and Labor Unions petitioned state legislatures, lobbied state and federal
politicians, and condemned manufacturers and purchasers of prison-made
products at rallies (Adamson, 1984). Organized labor had some success in
pressuring northern politicians who attempted to attract the labor vote,
but the political strength of the labor movement was not enough to rescind the use of prison labor (Barnes and Teeters, 1943). With the advent
of the Great Depression, organized labor was gaining power in the national politics and was able to influence federal legislation. The combination of economic slump and fierce political protest from organized labor,
small businesses, and humanist organizations forced Congress to pass a
series of laws which restricted prison labor (Barnes and Teeters, 1943).
The 1940 Sumners-Ashurst Act outlawed private sector use of prison
labor and interstate sales of prison-made products. For the next four decades, only the state-use system was in operation.
In 1979, Congress created the Prison Industry Enhancement Certification Program (PIECP), which again allowed certified businesses to
employ inmates and sell prisoner-made goods in interstate commerce.
The revival of private-sector prison labor served as a means to regulate
the economy and undermine union power (Adamson, 1984; Weiss, 2001).
During the late 1960s and early 1970s, unemployment was low and wages
continued to rise, and workers were engaging in strike activities at an
historically high rate (Parenti, 1999). The declining productivity and rising wage squeezed corporate profits, and the government began to seek
ways of using the growing pool of captive labor as an economic resource
(Adamson, 1984). Government officials and prison administrators began
to advocate private sector prison industry under the rhetoric of rehabilitation. Former Chief Justice Warren Burger forcefully advocated converting the U.S. prisons into “factories with fences,” which was welcomed by
the Reagan and Bush administrations (Buck, 1994).
Recent Developments
Eighty percent of federal and state prisoners work during their time
in prison. There are two general categories of work: non-industrial and

56

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

industrial work. The non-industrial work involves institutional maintenance and agriculture; the industrial work involves profitable production.
The majority of federal, state, and local inmates (40 to 66 percent) work
to maintain the operation of their institutions: janitorial duties, food
preparation, medical service, laundry, library, office help, recreation, barber, or beauty shop. The prison would not be able to function without
prisoner labor used for institutional maintenance (Burton-Rose, Pens,
and Wright, 1998). Very few (two percent of state prisoners) work on
prison farms: gardening, farming, forestry, ranching, and other agricultural activities. Federal and state inmates work an average of six hours
daily and receive $1.03 to $4.38 for non-industrial work (The Criminal
Justice Institute, 2000).
The most controversial form of prison labor is the prison industry,
employing inmates for profitable production and services. Currently, there
are three systems of prison industries: (1) the federal and state government-operated prison industry, (2) the PIECP, and (3) the prison industry operated by private prisons. The federal government and every state
government own and operate prison industries. The prison-made products, however, can be sold only to governmental agencies, public organizations, tax-supported entities, or markets in other countries. The PIECP
allows private corporations to enter “joint ventures” with state prisons for
profitable production; their products are sold in the free market.
The Federal Prison Industry
The largest government prison industry is the Federal Prison Industries (FPI), Inc., operating under the trade name UNICOR. It was established by Congress in 1934 and is a wholly owned government corporation within the U.S. Department of Justice. In 2000, the FPI operated
103 factories at 68 facilities within the Federal Prison System, offering
150 diverse products and services, and generated $546 million in net sales
and $17 million in profit (Federal Prison Industries, 2000). It employed
22,000 inmates (18 percent of federal inmates). Thirty percent of the
inmates work in textile, 22 percent in furniture, 18 percent in electronics, 16 percent in metals, and 14 percent in graphics and services. In
1999, the FPI paid $38 million, seven percent of its budget, on inmate
wages. The FPI workers work an average of 7.5 hours and receive a daily
wage ranging from $1.73 to $8.63 (see Table 1). Fifty percent of the inmate wages are garnished for court fines, child support, and victim restitution. After the deduction, the actual wage is miniscule.
With a growing federal prison population and expanding

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

57

58

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

opportunities in the service economy, the FPI attempted to expand its
operation and enter the commercial market. This has reignited the debate
over unfair labor and business competition, and brought two competing
bills under consideration in the 106th Congress. The Federal Prison
Industries Competition in Contracting Act of 1999 would restrict FPI by
requiring it to compete for government contracts and prohibiting it from
subcontracting products or services to the private sector. The bill was cosponsored by 30 unions, small businesses, and trade associations. The
Prison Industries Reform Act of 1999, however, would allow the FPI to
compete in the free market (Weiss, 2001).
The State Prison Industry
Every state prison operates its own prison industry. The most common products are wood/furniture, metal, paper/printing, vehicle-related,
and garment/textile. In 1999, state prison industries employed 56,000
inmates (seven percent of the state prison population) and generated $3
billion in sales and $67 million in profit. Inmates worked seven hours a
day and the daily wage ranged from $2.26 to $6.52. The gross wages paid
to inmates totaled $80 million and the net wages totaled $24 million.
The states garnished 70 percent of inmate wages for victim restitution,
child support, and cost of incarceration (The Criminal Justice Institute,
2000).
The largest state prison industry belongs to the Texas Correction
Industry (TCI). Established in 1963, TCI now has 43 facilities at 35 different Texas Department of Criminal Justice units, with the heaviest concentration in East Texas. These factories produce signage (metal and plastic), mattresses, shoes, garments, brooms, license plates, printed matter,
detergents, furniture, textile and steel products. In 2000, it used 7,000
inmates and generated $83 million in sales and $350,000 in profit. TCI,
however, does not pay its inmate workers wages (The Criminal Justice
Institute, 2000).
The PIECP
“If you are a labor-intensive business and need unskilled or semiskilled workers, you may want to operate in a Connecticut prison. We
supply the workers, the space and security. You supply the equipment,
supervise the eager and carefully screened workers, and control hiring and
termination,” advertises the Connecticut Department of Correction
(www.state.ct.us/doc/) as a participant of the PIECP. In 2001, 33 state

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

59

departments of corrections, four county facilities, and two privately operated facilities with a total of 159 private sector companies have been
certified by the program.
The PIECP operates under three models of partnership: employer
(62 percent of workers), customer (16 percent), and manpower (21 percent). The majority of workers work under the employer model—the state
prisons provide the space and a qualified pool of inmates, and private
corporations employ, supervise, and train its employees. Under the customer model, the company contracts with a prison or jail to provide a
finished product at an agreed upon price, and the prison owns and operates the business that employs, supervises, and trains the inmates. The
manpower model resembles temporary labor agencies. The companies lease
rather than employ their prison workforces (Sexton, 1995). The PIECP
requires participating businesses to pay workers the prevailing wage, provide benefits similar to government employees, meet the national Environmental Protection Act, consult with local organized labor and businesses, and not replace free workers. Worker participation is voluntary
but workers must contribute five percent to 20 percent of their gross
wages toward victim restitution programs. The total deduction, however,
cannot exceed 80 percent of inmates’ wages. The PIECP restrictions do
not apply to the service jobs and private correctional facilities.
According to Correctional Industries Association, more than 20,000
inmates have participated in PIECP since its inception in 1979. The
PIECP employed 900 inmates in 1991 and 3,700 in 2000, an average
annual growth of two percent. In 2000, 80 percent of the workers were
employed for manufacturing apparel, metal, electronic and electrical equipment, furniture, and wood products; 10 percent were employed for providing business and automobile services; and very few worked in agriculture and construction. The PIECP workers work an average of seven hours
a day and receive a daily wage range from $27.04 to $43.23 (The Criminal
Justice Institute, 2000). In 1999, the gross wage totaled $25 million and
the net wage totaled $9 million. Sixty-four percent of inmate wages are
garnished for taxes, room and board, and family support.
Escod Industries, a Fortune 500 conglomerate based in Columbus,
Ohio, is the largest PIECP employer with over 200 inmate workers. In
the early 1990s, South Carolina’s Division of Correctional Industries invited electronics company Escod to operate a plant inside a 1,100 bed
maximum/medium security prison at a time when the company was considering a satellite plant in Mexico. The company was immediately attracted
to the “cost-competitive” workforce that would better fit its “just-in-time”

60

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

production system than a plant located a thousand miles away. In 1994,
Escod’s prison employees assembled $16 million worth of electronic cables,
which were purchased by corporations such as IBM and the Canadian
Northern Telecom Corporation, which then uses Escod’s products in the
telephone cables it sells to several Eastern European countries (Sexton,
1995).
The Prison Industry Operated by Private Prisons
Similar to the public prisons, private prisons use the majority (65
percent) of the inmates’ labor for institutional maintenance, six percent
for prison industry, and 12 percent for prison farm work. Inmates work
longer hours, an average of eight hours, and receive lower daily wages,
from $0.96 to $3.20, than inmates in public prison industry. Private prisons also pay inmates at a lower rate for institutional maintenance than
the public prisons do (The Criminal Justice Institute, 2000).
Issues of Prison Industrialization
Both public and private sector prison industries face strong opposition, not only from labor, social, and political activists, but also from
business groups and trade organizations. Historically, organized labor emphasizes the adverse impact of prison labor on free workers’ job security,
wages, and working conditions, as well as the deprivation of prisoners’
work rights, benefits, and working conditions. Gallagher and Edwards
(1997) found that states with Democratic governors and strong labor
unions were more resistant to private prison industries. Testifying against
the Free-Market Prison Industries Reform Act of 1998, the AFL-CIO
stated:
The AFL-CIO and its affiliated unions, nationally and in the states,
have consistently supported efforts to provide training opportunities for prisoners to help in their rehabilitation, and to reduce
recidivism, but always with caution that prisoners should never be
used in competition with free labor or to replace free labor…
Twenty-one states have statutes that compel prisoners to work,
and others enforce policies that penalize inmates who refuse to
work…the use of inmate labor in this manner appears to violate
Convention No. 105 adopted by the International Labor Organization in 1957 and ratified by the United States in 1991, which
prohibits the use of forced prison labor for economic development…
The AFL-CIO calls on the federal government and the states to

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

61

end any promotional programs to encourage employers to set up
shop in federal or state prisons as an alternative to creating jobs
and hiring workers in the general population and in direct, intentional competition with private sector employers. (Smith, 1998)
So far, the economic impact of prison labor is small, but not trivial.
Economists calculate that even if all inmates worked, prison labor would
add only 0.2 to 0.4 percent of the total U.S. Gross Domestic Product
(Kling and Krueger, 1999). The current prison workforce (77,000 in public sector and 3,700 in private sector) is relatively small compared to the
civilian labor force of 135 million. Nevertheless, economists warn that a
significant increase in prison labor may displace the lowest unskilled strata
of the work force and depress their wages. If these displaced workers turn
to illegitimate means for economic survival, the social cost of the displacement is greater than the initial economic cost (Freeman, 1999). On
the other hand, jobs particularly suited to prison industry, usually laborintensive, low pay, and low-skill, are the types of jobs that are generally
relocated to Third World countries. Consequently, prison workers may be
competing with Third World free workers rather than domestic workers
(Misrahi, 1996; Parenti, 1999; Weiss, 2001).
Prisoner workers are deprived of rights to collective bargaining, minimum wage, unemployment compensation, worker’s compensation, and
workplace safety, except for the PIECP protection on prevailing wage and
worker’s compensation. In the 1977 Jones v. North Carolina Prisoner’s
Labor Union case, the Supreme Court, reversing the District Court decision, denied prisoners’ rights to organize and union activities. The Supreme Court upheld the right of the state to prohibit members of the
Prisoner’s Labor Union from soliciting other inmates to join the union,
to bar all union meetings, and to refuse to deliver union materials in the
mail. Prisoners who refuse to work, fail to meet production quotas, or
complain about working conditions are often denied privileges or benefits
(e.g., better housing assignments or extended visitation), or find themselves in solitary confinement. For example, in 1996 inmates of the Minnesota state prison industry were on a strike to demand minimum wage
and improvement in living conditions. Hours after the strike began,
prisoner’s cells were ransacked and alleged ringleaders were sent to disciplinary segregation. As more prisoners refused to work, the prison administration created more segregation units to house the strikers. No concessions were made (Burton-Rose, Pens and Wright, 1998). In support of
prison labor, neo-liberal economists and policy makers advocate the ex-

62

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

tension of employment legal rights, collective bargaining, minimum wage,
and workplace protections, to prison workers to “level the playing field”
(Marshall, 1999).
Nevertheless, some prisoners do “voluntarily” work for the prison
industries. Why would they take jobs that they would probably reject in
the free world even if paid a higher rate? In a coercive, isolated, and idle
penal environment, a monotonous and low wage job might appear to be
less alienating than a higher pay job in the free world. The wage offered by
government prison industries is so meager that the wages offered by the
private sector become attractive by comparison (Weiss, 2001). Although
a large percentage of their wages are garnished, prisoners may use the
remaining amount to purchase amenities that the state does not provide
and to accumulate savings to start a life upon release (Kalinich, 1980;
Misrahi, 1996).
Proponents of prison industries contend that the work programs
provide inmates with marketable skills and training, and consequently
reduce the recidivism rate. Wilson et al. (2000) found that participants of
work programs return to crime at a lower rate than non-participants.
However, the lower recidivism rate may result from background differences—those who participate in work programs are those who had legitimate jobs before they entered prisons. Moreover, most prison industries
offer only low-skill and labor-intensive jobs, which are unlikely to provide inmates marketable skills, training, or experience.
We have little knowledge of what criteria prison administrators use
to assign work. For rehabilitation purposes prison industries should employ inmates who have shorter sentences. But, to be profitable, prison
industries will likely hire inmates serving longer terms to reduce retraining and turnover costs. How is this conflict of interests reconciled in
assigning work? Moreover, the racial inequality in economic opportunities inside prison seems to mirror that of the free society. Jackson (1997)
showed racial disparity in job assignment—whites are more likely to be
assigned skilled jobs and earn higher hourly wages than are blacks. Consequently, blacks are more likely to engage in illegitimate economic activities, such as drug selling, prostitution, and theft, in prison to supplement
their income, which increases their misconduct reports, the loss of good
time and privileges, and their remaining time in prison (Kalinich, 1980).
Other critics condemn making profit from punishment as unethical or immoral. However, Parenti (1999) demonstrates that prison
industry is not as efficient and profitable as the opponents argue, due to
lack of space, stigma of prison-made products, security restrictions, loca-

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

63

tion problems, and poor quality of labor. This explains the slow growth of
the private sector prison industry. Parenti argues that the real function of
prison labor is ideological and political. Prison labor legitimizes the function of prison and fulfills the ideology of retribution and rehabilitation; it
makes the prison appear meaningful and it cures the illness of the “slacking” proletariat and the unfitness of character-flawed deviants. The prisonindustrial complex is a device for class and social control absent the drawback of empowerment associated with the welfare model. The PIECP is a
political instrument designed to promote the prison industrial complex
and yet satisfy every possible constituency: the state, the prison administrators, the prison guards, the victims, organized labor, and business.
Union Strategies and Dilemmas
Through effective coalition building, the labor movement has played
a key role in deterring the expansion of prison privatization and prison
industry (Gallagher and Edwards, 1997; Parenti, 1999). Organized labor’s
strategies, however, have been concentrated on political lobbying or
grassroots protests directly against prison privatization or prison industry.
These strategies are interest group-based, focusing on protecting the economic interests of union members or free labor. They accept the legitimacy of the skyrocketing incarceration rate. Such interest-based strategies will not likely thwart the mounting of corporate power in the criminal justice system in the long run.
The key to dismantling the prison industrial complex is
“decarceration” (Parenti, 1999). We propose a holistic approach to
“decarceration,” consisting of both criminal justice and non-criminal justice measures. The criminal justice approach involves decriminalizing certain non-violent behaviors, restricting availability of lethal weapons, and
seeking alternative institutions to incarceration. Parenti (1999) recommends fewer laws governing individual behaviors, less policing, and shorter
sentences. The majority of federal and state prisoners are non-violent
offenders (Beck and Harrison, 2001). This means that thousands of people
in prisons pose no threats to public safety. They are imprisoned because of
their socially “deviant” behaviors: lack of immigration documents, casual
drug use, mental illness, shoplifting, or homeless streetwalking. For example, in the past ten years, the growth rate of illegal immigration offenders is higher than that of violent offenders (Beck and Harrison, 2001).
Alternative institutions or programs, such as mental hospitals, drug-abuse
rehabilitation centers, homeless shelters, and vocational schools, can be
more effective in rehabilitation than is incarceration. While supporting

64

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

decriminalizing non-violent behaviors, we advocate more government
regulations on assault weapons to reduce violent crimes. The U.S. has the
highest death rate by firearms among industrialized countries and studies
show that regulation of gun ownership reduces violent crimes (Lott and
Mustard, 1997).
The non-criminal justice approach of “decarceration” involves developing other mechanisms for intervening the political economy: eliminating poverty, creating social and welfare programs, education, and job
opportunity for the unemployed, and raising the living wages and standards for the employed. Most of the prisoners were either the unemployed
or the working poor before they entered prisons. Jackson (1997) found
that over half of whites and Latinos and one-third of blacks had legitimate full-time employment before being incarcerated, but they were earning below poverty wage rates. Blacks’ median annual income was $6,750,
whites’ was $13,500, and Latinos’ was $8,750. Drug offenders attribute
drug selling to an unattractive labor market. They turned to the illegal
source of income as a means of “moonlighting” (Mauer, 2000). More attractive employment opportunities could prevent the underclass from turning to the underground economy.
The “decarceration” idea, however, may not draw consensus within
the labor movement because of internal racial, political, economic, cultural, and ideological divisions. For example, only recently has the AFLCIO recognized its “common bonds” with undocumented workers and
lobbied for amnesty legislation. Amnesty would decriminalize undocumented immigrants. “Decarceration” may conflict with the economic interests of segments of the labor movement—the loss of employment in
the highly unionized protective occupations, such as police and correctional officers. While strongly opposing prison privatization and prison
industries, organized labor often concurs with the “tough on crime” ideology. For example, CCPOA orchestrated Crime Victims United, a rightwing political action committee, pushing the passage of California’s “three
strikes” legislation. And, AFSCME has play a key role in passing the 1994
Crime Bill. Moreover, the public prison guards favor prison industry because inmates who are preoccupied by work are easier to manage than idle
inmates (Parenti, 1999).
The prison-industrial complex is an artifact of complex ideological,
social, political, and economic forces. Dismantling it requires fundamental changes in the class and racial relations. With dwindling union membership, the labor movement faces challenges and dilemmas in maximizing immediate economic interests of its members without sacrificing its

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

65

principles and its mission of building a social movement for social and
economic equality in a capitalistic society.
Acknowledgement
We would like to thank John Hagedorn, associate professor in the
Department of Criminal Justice at the University of Illinois at Chicago,
for his comments on earlier draft of this paper.
References
Adamson, Christopher. 1984. “Toward a Marxian Penology: Captive Criminal
Populations as Economic Threats and Resources.” Social Problems 31: 43558.
AFL-CIO. 2001. Prison Privatization. Online at www.afl-cio.org.
AFSCME. 2001. The Evidence is Clear: Crime Shouldn’t Pay. Online at
www.afscme.org.
Barlow, David E. and W. Wesley Johnson. 1996. “The Political Economy of
Criminal Justice Policy: A Time-Series Analysis of Economic Conditions,
Crime, and Federal Criminal Justice Legislation, 1948-1987.” Justice Quarterly 13: 223-41.
Barnes, Harry Elmer and Negley K. Teeters. 1943. New Horizons in Criminology:
The American Crime Problem. New York: Prentice-Hall, Inc.
Beck, Allen and Paige M. Harrison. 2001. “Prison and Jail Inmates in 2000.”
Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Justice.
Buck, Pem Davidson. 1994. “‘Arbeit Macht Frei’: Racism and Bound, Concentrated Labor in U.S. Prisons.” Urban Anthropology 23: 331-73.
Bureau of Justice Statistics. 2000. Sourcebook of Criminal Justice Statistics. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Justice.
Bureau of Labor Statistics. 2000. “Union Members.” Online at www.bls.gov/
news.release/union2.toc.htm.
Burton-Rose, Daniel, Dan Pens, and Paul Wright. 1998. The Celling of America.
Monroe, ME: Common Courage Press.
Chandler, Timothy D. 1994. “Sanitation Privatization and Sanitation Employees’ Wages.” Journal of Labor Research 15: 137-54.
Donahue, John D. 1989. The Privatization Decision. New York: Basic Books, Inc.
Federal Prison Industries, Inc. 2000. 2000 Annual Report. Washington, D. C.:
U.S. Department of Justice.

66

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002

Freeman, Richard B. 1999. “Making The Most From Prison Labor.” The National
Symposium on the Economics of Inmate Labor Force Participation. Washington,
D.C.
Gallagher, Daniel J. and Mary E. Edwards. 1997. “Prison Industries and the Private Sector.” Atlantic Economic Journal 25: 91-8.
Hagedorn, John M. 1998. “Gang Violence in the Postindustrial Era.” Crime and
Justice: A Review of Research 24: 365-419.
Hallett, Michael A. and J. Frank Lee. 2001. “Public Money, Private Interests:
The Grassroots Battle Against CCA in Tennessee.” Privatization in Criminal
Justice. D. Shichor and M. J. Gilbert, eds. Cincinnati, OH: Anderson Publishing Co.
Hirsch, Barry T. and Edward J. Schumacher. 2001. “Private Sector Union Density and the Wage Premium: Past, Present, and Future.” Journal of Labor
Research 22: 487-512.
Hochstetler, Andrew L. and Neal Shover. 1997. “Street Crime, Labor Surplus,
and Criminal Punishment, 1980-1990.” Social Problems 44: 358-68.
Jackson, Kevin L. 1997. “Differences in the Background and Criminal Justice
Characteristics of Young Black, White, and Hispanic Male Federal Prison
Inmates.” Journal of Black Studies 27: 494-508.
Jacobs, David and Ronald E. Helms. 1996. “Toward a Political Model of Incarceration: A Time-Series Examination of Multiple Explanations for Prison
Admission Rates.” American Journal of Sociology 102: 323-57.
Kalinich, David B. 1980. The Inmate Economy. Boston, MA: Lexington Books.
Kling, Jeffrey R. and Alan B. Krueger. 1999. “Cost, Benefits, and Distributional
Consequences of Inmate Labor.” The National Symposium on the Economics of Inmate Labor Force Participation. Washington, D.C.: The George
Washington University.
Lott, J. R. and D. B. Mustard. 1997. “Crime, Deterrence, and Right-to-Carry
Concealed Handguns.” Journal of Legal Studies 26: 1-68.
Marshall, Ray. 1999. “Preliminary Opinion on the Economics of Inmate Labor
Participation.” The National Symposium on the Economics of Inmate Labor Force Participation. Washington, D. C.
Mauer, Marc. 1999. The Race to Incarcerate. New York: The New Press.
_____. 2000. “Young Black Americans and the Criminal Justice System.” in
States of Confinement, edited by J. James. New York, NY: St. Martin’s.
Misrahi, James J. 1996. “Factories With Fences: An Analysis of The Prison Industry Enhancement Certification Program in Historical Perspective.” American Criminal Law Review 33.

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

67

Mobley, Alan and Gilbert Geis. 2001. “The Corrections Corporation of America
aka The Prison Realty Trust, Inc.” Privatization in Criminal Justice. D. Shichor
and M. J. Gilbert, eds. Cincinnati, Oh: Anderson Publishing Co.
Parenti, Christian. 1999. Lockdown America. New York, NY: Verso.
Scalia, John. 2001. “Federal Drug Offenders, 1999 with Trends 1984-1999.”
Washington, D.C.: Bureau of Justice Statistics.
Schlosser, Eric. 1998. “The Prison-Industrial Complex.” The Atlantic Monthly
282.
Schneider, Anne Larason. 2000. “Public-Private Partnership in the U.S. Prison
System.” Public-Private Policy Partnerships. P. V. Rosenau, ed. Cambridge,
MA: The MIT Press.
Sexton, George. 1995. “Work in American Prisons: Joint Ventures with the
Private Sector.” Washington, D.C.:U.S. Department of Justice.
Sheldon, Randall G. 2001. Controlling the Dangerous Classes. Boston: Allyn and
Bacon.
Smith, Davi A. 1998. “Prison Industry Programs: Effects on Inmates, Law-Abiding Workers, and Business.” Hearing before the Subcommittee on Oversights and Investigations of the Committee on Education and the Workforce,
House of Representatives, 105th Congress. Washington, D. C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
The Criminal Justice Institute. 2000. The Corrections Yearbook. Middletown, CT:
The Criminal Justice Institute, Inc.
Thomas, C. W. 2000. Private Adult Correctional Facility Census. Online at
www.web.crim.ufl.edu/pcp.
Weinberg, Daniel H. 1996. “Current Population Reports.” Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Census Bureau.
Weiss, Robert P. 2001. “Political Economy of Prison Labor Reprivatization in
the Postindustrial United States.” Criminology 39: 253-91.
Western, Bruce and Becky Pettit. 2000. “Incarceration and Racial Inequality in
Men’s Employment.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 54: 3-14.
Wilson, David B., Catherine A. Gallagher, and Doris L. MacKenzie. 2000. “A
Meta-Analysis of Corrections-Based Education, Vocation, And Work
Programs for Adult Offenders.” Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency
37: 347-68.
Wright, Paul 1997. “Profiting from Punishment.” Prison Labor News (March).

68

LABOR STUDIES JOURNAL: SPRING 2002
Appendix 1
Characteristics of Prison Privatization and Prison Industry by State

Region

State

Northeast

Connecticut
Yes
0
Maine
No
0.7
Massachusetts No
0
New Hampshire Yes
0
New Jersey
No
8.4
New York
Prohibition 0
Pennsylvania No
0
Rhode Island No
0
Vermont
No
0
Illinois
Prohibition 0
Indiana
Yes
4.9
Iowa
Permissive
0
Kansas
Permissive
0
Michigan
Yes
0.9
Minnesota
Permissive
0
Missouri
Permissive
0
Nebraska
Yes
0
North Dakota Permissive
8.9
Ohio
Yes
4.2
South Dakota No
1.7
Wisconsin
Yes
21.0
Alabama
No
0
Arkansas
Yes
12.3
Delaware
No
0
District of
31.4
Columbia
Florida
Yes
5.5
Georgia
Permissive
8.5
Kentucky
Yes
8.5
Louisiana
Yes
8.8
Maryland
Permissive
0.5
Mississippi
Yes
16.0
North Carolina Yes
1.1
Oklahoma
Yes
29.9
South Carolina Permissive
0
Tennessee
Yes
15.8
Texas
Yes
8.9

Midwest

South

Prison
Privatization
Law
(Statutory
Authority)

Percent
of Inmates
Held in
Private
Prison

Year of
Percent of
PIE
Inmates Work
Certification in State Prison
Industry

1989
1988
—1987
————1993
—1992
1992
1986
—1985
1989
1987
—1987
1991
1993
——1992
—1995
———1992
—1993
1987
1987
1991
1993

2.1
1.6
4.2
6.9
3.5
3.5
5.1
10.1
8.0
3.0
9.0
12.4
5.3
3.1
14.9
5.7
15.1
11.8
6.3
7.3
3.3
8.7
2.4
7.1
3.8
3.5
6.3
4.0
5.3
3.6
5.9
8.6
8.4
5.9
5.3

CORRECTIONAL INDUSTRY

West

Virginia
West Virginia
Alaska
Utah
Arizona
California
Colorado
Hawaii
Idaho
Montana
Nevada
New Mexico
Oregon
Washington
Wyoming

Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Permissive
Yes
Yes
Yes
Yes
Permissive
No
Yes

69
5.2
0
33.1
5.4
2.8
…
23.5
21.0
31.8
5.1
40.3
0
3.7
0
16.4

1995
—1989
1995
1991
1985
1990
1992
1986
1994
1985
1986
1989
1987
—-

4.2
7.7
5.9
15.5
5.6
3.9
6.5
8.5
12.5
7.6
3.7
9.3
5.2
13.0
7.9